The Money Price of Grains Regulates The Money Price of All Commodities
7 minutes • 1326 words
11 The real effect of the bounty is not so much to raise the real value of wheat as to degrade the real value of silver.
It makes silver buy less wheat and other home-made commodities because the money price of wheat regulates the money price of all other home-made commodities.
12 The money price of wheat regulates the money price of labour.
The money price of labour must always enable the labourer to buy sufficient wheat to maintain him and his family in the liberal, moderate, or scanty manner which the advancing, stationary, or declining state of society oblige his employers to maintain him.
13 The money price of wheat regulates the money price of all other rude produce of land.
The money price of all other rude produce must bear a certain proportion to the money price of wheat. Though this proportion is different in different periods of improvement.
For example, the money price of wheat regulates the money price of:
- grass and hay,
- meat,
- horses,
- the maintenance of horses
- land carriage, and
- most of the inland commerce of the country.
14 By regulating the money price of all other rude produce of land, the money price of wheat regulates the materials of almost all manufactures.
By regulating the money price of labour, the money price of wheat regulates the money price of manufacturing and industry.
By regulating the money price of manufacturing and industry, the money price of wheat regulates the money price of complete manufactures.
The money price of labour and all produce of land or labour, must rise or fall in proportion to the money price of wheat.
15 Because of the bounty, the farmer can sell his wheat for 48 pence a bushel instead of 42 pence.
He can pay his landlord a money rent proportional to this rise. But because of this rise in wheat prices, 48 pence will buy what 42 pence bought before.
The circumstances of the farmer or the landlord will not be much improved by this change.
The farmer will not be able to cultivate much better.
The landlord will not be able to live much better.
This enhancement in wheat prices may give them some little advantage in buying foreign commodities.
But it can give them no advantage in buying home-made commodities.
Almost the whole expence of the farmer and most of the expence of the landlord is in home-made commodities.
16 The degradation in the value of silver caused by the fertility of the mines has very little consequence to any country.
The consequent rise of all money prices, does not make sellers of silver richer.
It makes them really poorer.
A service of plate becomes really cheaper.
Everything else remains precisely of the same real value as before.
17 But that local degradation in the value of silver caused by a country’s political institutions has a very great consequence which makes everybody really poorer.
The rise in the money price of all commodities in a country discourages its industry.
It allows foreign nations to:
- produce those commodities with less money, and
- consequently, undersell the country in the foreign and home markets.
18 This is the situation of Spain and Portugal.
They are the proprietors of the mines and the distributors of gold and silver to all European countries.
Those metals are naturally cheaper in Spain and Portugal than in any part of Europe.
The difference should be no more than the cost of the freight and insurance.
- The freight of gold and silver is no great matter due to their small bulk.
- Their insurance is the same as other goods of equal value.
Spain and Portugal could suffer very little from their situation if their institutions did not aggravate its disadvantages.
19 Spain taxes the exportation of gold and silver while Portugal bans it.
They load that exportation with the cost of smuggling.
They raise the value of those metals in other countries by this cost.
When you dam up a stream of water, water must run over as soon as the dam is full, as much as if there was no dam at all.
The ban on exportation cannot keep more gold and silver in Spain and Portugal than what is needed for coin, plate, gilding, and other ornaments.
When they have got this amount, the dam is full. The stream which flows in must run over.
Despite the restraints, the exports of gold and silver from Spain and Portugal is nearly equal to its imports.
The water must always be deeper behind the dam-head than before it. Likewise, the amount of gold and silver detained in Spain and Portugal must be more than the gold and silver in other countries, relative to their national annual produce. The higher and stronger the dam-head, the greater the difference in the depth of water inside and outside of it.
The higher the tax:
- the higher the penalties imposed by the ban
- the more vigilant and severe must the police be
- the greater must be the difference in the proportion of gold and silver to the national produce of Spain and Portugal compared to that of other countries.
The difference is very considerable.
There is a profusion of plate in houses in Spain and Portugal where nothing could be suitable in other countries.
The cheapness of gold and silver is the same thing as the dearness of all commodities.
The cheapness of those metals is the effect of this redundancy of those metals. It discourages the agriculture and manufactures of Spain and Portugal. It enables foreign nations to supply them rude and manufactured produce for fewer gold and silver than what Spain and Portugal can themselves raise or make at home.
The tax and prohibition operate in 2 ways:
- They very much lower the value of the precious metals in Spain and Portugal
- They detain an amount which would have flown to other countries.
- They keep up the value of gold and silver in other countries higher than natural
- They give those countries a double advantage in their commerce with Spain and Portugal.
Open the floodgates, and there will be less water above and more below the dam-head. It will soon come to a level in both places.
Remove the tax and the prohibition and the amount of gold and silver will:
- reduce considerably in Spain and Portugal
- increase in other countries
The value of those metals will soon come to a level in all countries, proportional to the national annual produce of each.
The loss which Spain and Portugal sustains by this exportation would be nominal and imaginary.
The nominal value of their goods and their national annual produce would fall.
It would be expressed in fewer silver than before.
But their real value would be the same.
It would maintain, command, and employ, the same amount of labour.
As the nominal value of their goods would fall, the real value of the remaining gold and silver would rise.
Fewer of those metals would be needed for commerce and for circulating commodities than before.
The gold and silver which would go abroad would not go abroad for nothing.
They would would bring back goods of equal value.
Those goods would not all be goods of luxury and expense to be consumed by idle people who produce nothing in return.
This exportation of gold and silver will not increase the real wealth and revenue of idle people.
It will not increase their consumption.
Most of the imported goods would probably consist in raw materials, tools, and provisions, for the employment of industrious people. Those people would reproduce the full value of their consumption, with a profit.
A part of society’s dead stock would thus be turned into active stock.
It would mobilize more industry than before.
Their national annual produce would immediately increase a little, but would increase very much after a few years. Their industry would be relieved from a very oppressive burden.